A growing
number of scientific researchers and political leaders have urged prompt
conservation of fossil fuels by investing immediately in energy-efficient
vehicles, machinery, and structures and by gradually shifting to alternative
sources of energy.
This
argument, although drawn from recent research on the economics of technology,
offers important lessons to the environmental and resource economist. Fossil
fuel conservation would postpone the historical moment when widespread
commercial adoption of a replacement energy technology must occur. This
postponement, in turn, would permit society to assemble a more extensive
portfolio of potential replacement technologies that have already completed
their pre-commercial phases of development. Hence, comparisons of input costs,
social implications, and environmental hazards associated with the various
options could be made, at least in principle, prior to commercialization of,
and possibly irreversible commitment to, a particular replacement technology.
Having time to compare and assess potential candidates to replace fossil fuels
is especially important since, as Georgescu Roegen (1971) has wisely observed,
not all technologies that are feasible to operate in the short run are also
viable in the long run.
This
chapter discusses the effects of fossil fuel power plants, or simply the
burning of fossil fuels to our environment.
It indicates here the many disadvantages of using such substances like
its bad effects on human health, animal life and our ozone layer. However, the actions being taken to prevent
these effects are also shed light in this paper through the programs of the
Environment Protection Agency.
Background of the Literature
Environmental
protection requirements imposed on fossil-fuel electric power generators by the
United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) are subject to ongoing
review because this is the industry most responsible for conventional air pollutant
emissions and is a significant source category of hazardous air pollutants (Reitze, 2002). Fossil fuels are used to generate about 68% of the electricity
in the United States; coal is used to generate about 44% of the electricity (U.S. Dep't of Energy, 2001). In 1998, electric
utilities emitted 67.2% of the nation's S[O.sub.2], 24.9% of N[O.sub.x], and
about 10.6% of the small particulate (P[M.sub.10]) emissions (U.S.
Environmental protection Agency, 2000).
Most important
environmental impacts caused by energy sources are global climate change and
acid rain – both of which have the origin in the combustion of fossil fuels and
lead to global or transboundary effects. (Falk, 2000). Combustion of fossil
fuels contributes around 80 percent to total world-wide anthropogenic CO2
emissions. Since the industrial revolution, humans have been adding huge
quantities of greenhouse gases, especially carbon dioxide (CO2) to the
atmosphere. More greenhouse gases means that more heat is trapped, which causes
global warming. By burning coal, oil and natural gas increases atmospheric
concentrations of these gases. Over the past century, increases in industry,
transportation, and electricity production have increased gas concentrations in
the atmosphere faster than natural processes can remove them leading to
human-caused warming of the globe (Falk, 2000).
Moreover,
sixty-seven hazardous air pollutants potentially are emitted from fossil-fueled
electric power generating plants, and EPA predicts a 30% increase in these emissions
by the year 2010 (US Environmental Protection Agency, 1998). In addition, about
40% of C[O.sub.2] from United States sources comes from electric power industry
(utilities and nonutilities combined), (US Environmental Protection Agency,
2001) and domestic C[O.sub.2] emissions increased by 2.5% in 2000, which is a
significant increase from the 1.3% average annual growth from 1990 to 2000
(Bologna, 2001).
The United
States's emissions of C[O.sub.2] are responsible for an estimated 25% of the
world's C[O.sub.2] emissions from fossil-fuel burning and cement manufacturing
(United Nations Programme, 2001). Moreover, increases in generating capacity
are projected to increase C[O.sub.2] from the electricity sector by 14 to 38%
by 2007 from the 1998 level. In 1999, coal was used to generate 52.8% of the
electricity generated in the United States; petroleum was used to produce
2.56%; and natural gas was used to produce 10.78% (US Department of Energy,
2001).
The use of
natural gas is projected to increase, coal use will increase more slowly, and
petroleum use is expected to continue to decrease (US Department of Energy,
2001). Most of the nation's coal-burning plants were constructed between 1950
and 1980, and these plants are the nation's most significant stationary source
of air pollution (Swift, 2000). New electric power plants almost always use
gas-fired turbines because such plants are less expensive to construct, have a
higher thermal efficiency, and produce far less pollution. This offsets the
need for gas, which is more expensive than coal (US Department of Energy,
2000).
In
2001, there were more than five thousand electric power planks in the United
States (Reitze, 2002). However, the
field is dominated by a small number of investor-owned and publicly-owned
utilities. In 1995, investor-owned utilities accounted for more than 75% of
retail electric power sales and revenues. Ten companies accounted for 32.61% of
the revenue from investor-owned electric utilities, over $53 billion dollars.
Publicly-owned electric utilities accounted for about one-eighth of the revenue
from electric power sales; nearly half of the publicly-owned generation sales
came from ten utilities. Because the electric power industry is such an
important stationary air emissions source, and because it represents the most
cost effective target for major reductions of N[O.sub.x] and S[O.sub.2]
emissions, much of the CAA program for stationary sources is aimed at
controlling this industry (Parker and Blodgett, 2001).
Review of the Literature
The burning of fossil fuels
has a number of potential undesirable effects: high levels of urban air
pollution; acid rain that damages forests, lakes, and crops; and changes in
global climate. Exposure to high levels of particulates in urban air causes
hundreds of thousands of premature deaths and millions of cases of respiratory
illness worldwide (World Bank 1994; 1997c; WHO 1997).
The
reason most commonly given in support of fossil fuel conservation is the need
to prevent future global climate change. The World Resources Institute [1992,
2-7], for instance, argues that fossil fuels provide about 95 percent of the
commercial energy used in the world economy. Combustion of those fuels
constitutes the largest source of emissions of climate-altering greenhouse
gases. Most scientists agree that such emissions cannot be continued
indefinitely at current or increasing levels without causing devastating
effects on ecosystems and on people (WRI, 1992).
It is
now widely acknowledged that the depletion of geological stocks of fossil
hydrocarbons will eventually force the global economy to shift to an
alternative energy technology (England,
1994). Several transitional strategies have been proposed to facilitate
the historic shift from fossil fuels to their eventual replacement(s). The
World Resources Institute 11992, 22!, for example, emphasizes the immediate
potential for increased energy efficiency. They asserted that there is no lack
of technological opportunity for more efficient energy use in the United States
and other OECD countries.
Meadows
et al. [1992, 74] also reflect this point of view. The Worldwatch Institute, on
the other hand, has recently proposed natural gas as a relatively benign
substitute for oil and coal during the next two decades, especially in light of
a substantial increase in global proven reserves of natural gas during recent
years [Flavin 1992, 28].
At
any moment in time, then, the alternative energy technologies that might
replace fossil fuels are suspended between their known historical records and
their uncertain future possibilities. Some are at an early stage of their
technological evolution, awaiting fundamental advances in science, mathematics,
computing, and laboratory instrumentation. Others are at the later stage of
prototype testing and have begun to attract the attention of innovation-minded
entrepreneurs and venture capitalists (England, 1994).
The
locus of environmental policy is increasingly situated at the state level (Ptoski and Woods, 2002). In clean air policy, states conduct the bulk
of the enforcement actions, operate an extensive network of air monitoring
stations, and have adopted pollution standards that often exceed the U.S.
Environmental Protection Agency's (USEPA) minimum criteria (Ptoski and Woods, 2002). However, state environmental programs are not
uniform, particularly in air pollution regulation. Some states have adopted
more stringent air quality standards, others have developed more rigorous
enforcement regimes, while still others have cultivated reputations for
technical policy expertise. Analysts attempting to explain differences in state
environmental programs have developed a standard set of tools of inquiry that
they have employed both to measure the vigor, or "greenness," of
state environmental programs and to explain why states adopt differing policy
programs (Ptoski and Woods, 2002).
Thus,
the electric power industry is changing rapidly. Two laws--the Public Utility
Regulatory Policy Act of 1978 (PURPA) (24) and the Energy Policy Act of 1992
(EPAct) (25)--started the move toward increased competition in the electric
power industry. EPAct removed constraints on ownership of electric power
generator facilities and encouraged competition in the wholesale electric power
business (Reitze, 2002).
To
comply with State Implementation Plant requirements, fossil-fuel electric power
generating plants have to meet the CAA requirements applicable to stationary
sources, but due to the large portion of stationary source emissions
attributable to the electric power industry, there are provisions in the CAA
aimed primarily at this industry. Moreover, because of the size of most
electric power plants, the more stringent requirements imposed on major sources
usually are applicable.
The
684 coal-fired electric power plants in the United States emit trace amounts of
sixty-seven air toxics, (Clean Air Act, 2000) according to a 1998 EPA report. Of the thirty-three
chemicals listed for control under EPA's Urban Air Toxics Strategy, most are
emitted from fossil-fuel electric generating plants US Environmental
Protection Agency, 1998). According to EPA (1998),
most of the inhalation health risk comes from arsenic and chromium emissions,
but the agency also is concerned about mercury and dioxins emissions. For
oil-fired utilities, nickel creates the greatest inhalation risk (EPA, 1998).
Mercury emissions are considered the most significant pollutant for
multi-pathway analysis because they bioaccumulate in the food web (EPA,
1998).
To
form a picture of carbon use, we need to be able to sum and compare its
appearances. One way is to index carbon by the ratio of carbon atoms to
hydrogen atoms in the energy sources that contain both of these fuels (Nakicenovic, 1996). Fuelwood has the highest effective carbon
content, with about ten carbon atoms per hydrogen atom. If consumed without a
compensating growth of biomass, which occurred in the past and still occurs in
most developing countries, fuelwood thus produces higher carbon emissions than
any of the fossil energy forms. Among fossil energy sources, coal has the
highest carbon-to-hydrogen ratio, roughly one to one. Oil has on average one
carbon for every two hydrogen atoms, and natural gas, or methane, has a ratio
of one to four. Using these types of elemental analyses, we can estimate the
total amount of carbon contained in a given supply of an individual fuel or a
mix of fuels and compare this amount to energy consumed or associated economic
output (Nakicenovic, 1996).
Decarbonization
can then be expressed as a product of two factors: 1) carbon emissions per unit
of energy consumption (Nakicenovic,
1996);
and 2) energy requirements per unit of value added, which is often called
energy intensity (Nakicenovic,
1996).
The ratio of carbon emissions per unit of primary energy consumed globally has
fallen by about 0.3 percent per year since 1860 (Nakicenovic, 1996). The ratio has decreased because those with
lower carbon content, such as gas, have continuously replaced high-carbon
fuels, such as wood and coal, and also in recent decades by nuclear energy from
uranium and hydropower, which contain no carbon (Nakicenovic, 1996).
The
major determinants of energy-related carbon emissions can be represented as
multiplicative factors in a simple equation. Placing carbon emissions on one
side, on the other we have population growth, per capita value added, energy
consumption per unit of value added, and carbon emissions per unit of energy
consumed (Nakicenovic, 1996). However, their
decline is counteracted by rising values for the preceding terms, population
and economic activity, resulting in an overall global increase in energy
consumption and carbon emissions.
The
competitive struggle between the five main sources of primary energy--wood,
coal, oil, gas, and nuclear--has proven to be a dynamic and regular process
that can be described by relatively simple rules (Nakicenovic, 1996). A glance reveals the dominance of coal as the
major energy source between the 1880s and the 1960s after a long period during
which fuelwood and other traditional energy sources led. The mature coal
economy meshed with the massive expansion of railroads and steamship lines, the
growth of steelmaking, and the electrification of factories. During the 1960s,
oil assumed a dominant role in conjunction with the development of automotive
transport, the petrochemical industry, and markets for home heating oil (Nakicenovic, 1996).
The model of
energy substitution projects natural gas (methane) to be the dominant source of
energy during the first decades of the next century, although oil should
maintain the second largest share until the 2020s (Nakicenovic, 1996). Such an exploratory look requires additional assumptions
to describe the later competition of potential new energy sources such as
nuclear, solar, and other renewables that have not yet captured sufficient
market shares to allow reliable estimation of their penetration rates (Nakicenovic, 1996). This leaves natural gas with the largest share of primary
energy for at least the next fifty years. In the past, new sources of energy
have emerged from time to time, coinciding with the saturation and subsequent
decline of the dominant competitor.
In
fact, an energy system of the distant future that relies on electricity and
hydrogen as the complementary energy carriers would also advance
dematerialization (Nakicenovic,
1996).
Hydrogen has the lowest mass of all atoms, and its use would radically reduce
the total mass flow associated with energy activities and the resulting
emissions. Electricity is free of material emissions, and the only product of
appropriate hydrogen combustion is water.
It
can now be seen that, even if humanity could adapt costlessly to global climate
change, accelerating global consumption of fossil fuels would still have an
ominous consequence: rapid arrival of the "moment of decision" when
widespread commercial adoption of some alternative energy technology would be
essential to continued economic activity (England, 1994). A second reason for
promoting immediate conservation of fossil fuels is to give humanity more time
to construct the social institutions and cultural values that would be
compatible with a post-fossil fuel technology, thereby mitigating the social
dislocations and conflicts that will inevitably accompany that technological
transformation (England, 1994). There is, however, a third reason to pursue
fossil fuel conservation, which is rooted in concerns about the present
generation: the need to avert increasingly violent wars over control of the
world's dwindling stock of unused petroleum (England, 1994).
By
2006-2011, electricity will be purchased and sold in both wholesale and
eligible retail markets by
any willing creditworthy participant (Tomain, 2002). Markets will clear with
competitive prices. Competitive prices will function so as
to ration existing supplies efficiently
in the short run and to elicit
adequate technology and infrastructure
in the long run, so that there will
be no involuntary curtailment of service
at market prices (Tomain, 2002). Electricity markets will be
both transparent and liquid, and market participants will
have opportunities to hedge risks.
Although regulation of monopoly service
providers will continue, even these
monopolies will feel some pressure of
competitive market forces (Loomis,
1998).
The EPA as the Mitigating Agency
for Environment Protection
With the
kind of environmental problems outlined above, a government program that will
focus in the prevention, restoration and regulation of these environmental
nuisances is a required. Thus the Environmental Protection Agency was
established to meet these challenges. As such, several programs were instituted
that responds on issues covering water, air and land degradation.
One such
program is the EPA’s Clean Energy Programs. It is designed to improve the
national foundation of information on Clean Energy by creating networks between
the public and private sector, providing technical assistance, and offering
recognition of environmental leaders that adopt Clean Energy practices.
Moreover, Climate Leaders is a voluntary EPA industry-government partnership
that encourages companies to develop long-term comprehensive climate change
strategies. Combined Heat and Power (CHP) is one form of distributed generation
that produces electricity at the point of use. CHP, or cogeneration, is the
sequential production of electricity and thermal energy from a single fuel
source. CHP is more efficient, cleaner, and reliable than conventional central
power plants. The CHP Partnership is a voluntary program that seeks to reduce
the environmental impact of power generation by fostering the use of CHP in the
commercial, institutional, and industrial sectors.
As a
result, there has been substantial environmental progress over the past several
decades (Adler, 2001). Air and water
quality, in particular, have improved, while the United States and other
nations have reached unprecedented levels of prosperity (Adler, 2001).
However,
environmental regulation imposes a large and growing burden on the United
States economy (Adler, 2001). In 1999, environmental regulations cost an
estimated $206 billion -- over one-quarter of the total federal regulatory
burden (Adler, 2001). In late 1999, the EPA's accounted for over ten percent of
all new rules in the regulatory pipeline.(17) Of the 137 forthcoming major
rules identified by the federal government in October 1999, the EPA accounted
for twenty-eight, over twenty percent of the total, and more than any other
federal agency (Adler, 2001).
Environmental
regulations are certainly costly (Adler, 2001). However, there is no question
that the early environmental laws seemed to work well (Meiner, 1993). Beginning
in the 1960s, many indicators of environmental quality showed distinct
improvement (Portney, 2000). Some of these gains were likely due to the first
generation of federal environmental regulation. The rest occurred due to state
and local efforts or other extraneous factors (Portney, 2000). The initial
generation of environmental policy was effective principally because it was
plucking low-hanging fruit; removing lead from gasoline and preventing the
disposal of raw sewage in rivers were relatively easy issues to address.
As of June
30, 1999, the Environmental Protection Agency ("EPA") claimed to have
cleaned up half of the over 1,200 sites on the National Priorities List
("NPL") -- the EPA's official list of the most hazardous waste sites
-- yet fewer than 200 had been actually taken off the list (GAO, 1999).
There
are two primary obstacles to successful government efforts to promote clean
technologies (Goodstein, 1995). First, assuming
that government planners are in fact public spirited, they face poor
information about the environmental consequences of a given technology as well
as future production costs and markets. This suggests a potential for mistakes,
which as noted above, may be costly. Second, once given significant power to
pick technologies for promotion, government planners will in fact face a
variety of political-economic motivations to deviate from serving the general interest
(Goodstein, 1995).
The
administrative system for environmental policy in the United States is a mix of
centralized and decentralized (Lotspeich, 1998). While states have a great deal
of independence and primary responsibility for implementation and enforcement,
environmental standards typically are determined at the federal level by the
EPA (Lotspeich, 1998). A more intrusive approach to regulation of private
enterprise in the United States has been noted by several researchers of
comparative politics, and in particular by Vogel (1986) for the case of
environmental regulation. He asserts that the use of emissions charges has been
very limited in the United States, being restricted to wastewater effluents.
These charges are administered locally, their primary purpose is to fund
treatment plants, and usually they are not tied directly to effluent volumes.
As incentive impacts are negligible, these charges don't really represent
application of market instruments for pollution control. In keeping with a philosophy
contrary to government support of private industry, the only significant
subsidy program in U.S. environmental policy has been intergovernmental
transfers in the form of federal grants to local governments for the
construction of wastewater treatment facilities (Lotspeich, 1998).
In the late 1970s the EPA began to experiment with flexibility in
emission standards for air pollutants, and legislation in 1986 formalized
procedures for quasi-tradable permit systems referred to as the bubble, offset,
netting, and banking provisions (Lotspeich, 1998). Banking allows a firm
temporarily to store emission reduction credits, and the other three elements
are different applications of tradable permits (Lotspeich, 1998). The offset
program allows trades between existing and new sources, while the bubble policy
provides for trades among existing sources. The netting program pertains to
equipment modifications within a given production facility (Lotspeich, 1998).
Several observers argue that these programs are not as successful as they could
be. Although their introduction has moved policy toward tradable permit
systems, they have been criticized as unduly restrictive and excessively
bureaucratic. Trades are subject to extensive regulatory reviews, approval
typically takes from 4 to 29 months, and trade brokers have emerged in response
to the high cost of trading (Opschoor & Vos, 1989). Of the several thousand
offset trades completed by the late 1980s only 100 were at "arm's
length" (Dudek & Palmisano, 1988), which suggests that administrative
srequirements are biased in favor of internal shifts of abatement
responsibility. High transaction costs likely are preventing mutually
beneficial trades between separate firms that would reduce overall compliance
cost.
Despite
limitations on trading, these policies have helped achieve major cost savings.
With the flexibility they introduce, firms are less tied to particular control
technologies, which is especially important because policy in the United States
has been technologically restrictive (Lotspeich, 1998). There also is scope for
shifting abatement burdens from high-cost to low-cost sources. The extent to
which limited trading is able to exploit the potential cost saving is not known
fully, but several studies have indicated that significant reductions in
compliance cost have resulted (Dudek & Palmisano, 1988). Hahn &
I-lester (1989) estimated over $400 million of savings by the 132 trades that
had occurred under the bubble program and as much as several billions of dollars
by the thousands of trades carried out under the netting program. Their
analysis concluded that the following features are important for success: low
levels of political conflict, low information requirements for firms, lessened
regulatory delay, security in the property right, and the existence of
facilitating institutions that function as a trading infrastructure. These
features are basic to economic exchange more generally.
Activities EPA considers in
keeping with the exemption include: monitoring the borrower's business;
conducting on-site inspections and audits; and certification of financial
information and legal compliance. The underlying proviso is that the borrower
remain in "possession and control" of the facility (ABA Banking Journal, 1990).
References:
Adler,
Jonathan, Free and green: a new approach to environmental protection, Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy,
Vol. 24, 2001
Bologna, Michael, U.S. C[O.sub.2]
Emissions Up 3.1 Percent in 2000, Total Greenhouse
Gas Emissions Also Grow, Daily Env't Rep. (BNA), Nov. 13, 2001.
Carol J. Loomis, A House
Built on Sand, FORTUNE, Oct. 26, 1998, at 110.
Dudek, D. J., & Palmisano, J. (1988).
Emissions trading: Why is this thoroughbred
hobbled? Columbia Journal of Environmental Law, 13 (2), 217-256.
Electric utility steam-generating unit
is defined at Clean Air Act, 42 U.S.C. [section]
7412(a)(8) (2000).
England,
Richard, Three reasons for investing now in fossil fuel conservation: technological lock-in, institutional
inertia, and oil wars, Journal of Economic
Issues, Vol. 28, 1994
EPA
rule could ease toxic risks, ABA Banking Journal, Vol. 82, 1990
Falk. Hakan, “Energy Saving Now –
Effects of Energy Use,” Energy Saving, Energey
Saving. Nu, 2000
Flavin, Christopher. "Building a
Bridge to Sustainable Energy." In State of the World 1992, edited by Worldwatch Institute staff, 27-45. New
York: W.W. Norton, 1992.
GAO,
Superfund: Half the Sites Have All Cleanup Remedies in Place or Completed, GAO/RCED-99-245, July 1999, at
5.
Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas. The Entropy
Law and the Economic Process. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press, 1971.
Goodstein, Eban, The economic roots of environmental decline: property rights or path dependence?, Journal of Economic
Issues, Vol. 29, 1995
Hahn, R. W., & Hester, G. L. (1989).
Marketable permits: Lessons for theory and practice.
Ecology Law Quarterly, 16(2), 361-406.
Lotspeich, Richard, Comparative
environmental policy: market-type instruments in
industrialized capitalist countries, Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 26, 1998
Meadows, Donella, Dennis Meadows, and
Jorgen Randers. Beyond the Limits. Post
Mills, Vt.: Chelsea Green, 1992.
Meiner,
Roger E. & Yandle, Bruce, Clean Water Legislation: Reauthorize or Repeal?, in TAKING THE ENVIRONMENT
SERIOUSLY 73, 86-87 (Roger E.
Meiners & Bruce Yandle eds., 1993).
Nakicenovic,
Nebojsa, Freeing energy from carbon, Daedalus, Vol. 125, 1996 Parker, Larry and Blodgett, John, Air Quality and
Electricity Initiatives to increase
Pollution Controls 4, 2001.
Opschoor, J. B., & Vos, H. B. (1989).
Economic instruments for environmental protection.
Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Portney, Paul, Air Pollution Policy, in
PUBLIC POLICIES FO ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION 98 (Paul Portney ed., 2d ed. 2000).
(25.)
Ptoski,
Matthew, and Woods, Neal, Dimensions of state environmental policies: air pollution regulation in the United
States, Policy Studies Journal, Vol. 30,
2002
Reitze, Arnold, State and federal
command-and-control regulation of emissions from
fossil-fuel electric power generating plants, Environmental Law, Vol. 32, 2002
Swift, Byron, Grandfathering, New Source
Review, and N[O.sub.x]—Making Sense
of a Flawed System, Daily Env't Rep. (BNA), July 14, 2000, at B-1, WL 136 DEN B-1, 2000.
Tomain,
Joseph, The past and future of electricity regulation, Environmental Law, Vol. 32, 2002
U.S. Dep't of Energy, Office of Fossil
Energy, Latest EIA Coal Facts, 44 Clean Coal
Today 11 (2001)
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency,
national Air Quality and Emission Trends Report
1998, at 122, 124, 125 (2000)
United Nations Programme, World
Resources 2000-2001, People and Ecosystems:
The Fraying Webs of Life 282-283, 2001.
US Department of Energy, Annual Energy
Outlook 2000 With Projections to 2020,
pp 68 (2000).
US Department of Energy, Energy
Information Agency, Reducing Emissions of Sulfur
Dioxide, Nitrogen Oxides, and Mercury From Electric Power Plant, 2001
US Environmental Protection Agency,
Inventory of US Greenhouse Gas Emissions
and Sinks: 1990-1999 ES-12 (2001).
US Environmental Protection Agency,
National Air Quality and Emission Trends Report
1997, 82, 1998.
Vogel, D. (1986). National styles of
regulation: Environmental policy in Great Britain
and the United States. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
World Resources Institute. World
Resources 1992-93. New York: Oxford University
Press, 1992.
No comments:
Post a Comment